It’s been so long since I wrote in this space, or any space, that I can’t remember how to string words together. But I want to respond to something in the Washington Post last week, a letter to the editor that struck me, from a gentleman named Mark Swierczek, which was itself responding to a previous letter from Robert Sutton. Both letters were expounding on the value and inevitability of income and wealth inequality in any free society. And both seem to me to suffer from a special form of self-inflicted ideological blindness that appears, if looked at with gauzy, vacant eyes, like clean and simple logic.
Here’s what they said, in their words. From Robert Sutton:
“Income inequality is the
natural, expected and welcome consequence of an economically free
society. Absent the shackles of an overreaching government and social
engineers, income will flow to those with greater talents, greater intelligence
and the strong work ethic to use their God-given blessings. Governments
that try to reverse that flow will be forever tilting at windmills, since
nature never will stop working against them.”
And from Mark Swierczek:
“Income inequality is, in fact,
the force that drives our economy. By rewarding achievement, income inequality
provides the motivation for people to work hard and be successful, much as
winner-take-all prizes in sporting events lead to the most-contested,
best-played games.
In a free market, income
inequality is also self-correcting since, as people work their way to the upper
end of the income range, inequality is naturally reduced. Programs
intended to reduce inequality via artificial means, on the other hand, tend to
reduce economic incentive and therefore perpetuate the very inequality they are
intended to address.”
These two letter writers believe that
inequality is acceptable, even virtuous, because it is the combination of an
unequal distribution of virtue combined with virtue-dependent economic
mobility. And there is a morsel of
simple truth, of common experience, in that, which makes it appealing. People who work harder, with better
attitudes, and who have better educations, do seem to get ahead faster, on
average, than those who are lazy, or ignorant, or sullen. But why are they telling us this obvious
thing? I think they’re arguing against
a proposition that no prominent economist, politician or columnist has ever
made: no one wants to impose absolute income or wealth equality, and no
columnist I have read has proposed that we eliminate differential rewards for
hard work, intelligence or creativity. We’ve
always had income differences, and for large periods of our history that has
been unremarked, because it was unremarkable.
The alarm, when it has been sounded at all, is about the rapid increase in income inequality in the
last thirty-five years; it is that all of the benefits of growth, and of
increased labor productivity, over those thirty-five years have flowed to the
very top of the income scale, and not to the labor whose production has
increased. It’s about the rapid cultural
change that has been highlighted in the work of Thomas Piketty from the Paris
School of Economics and Emmanuel Saez at the University of California at
Berkely, which showed in graphs that after a long period of relatively
egalitarian economic growth we have now returned to the kind of income
inequality that characterized the gilded age.
A graph like this, using data from Piketty and Saez, was posted in the very
first post in Paul Krugman’s NYT blog.
There’s a great deal to say about the
potential negative economic impacts of income inequality that balance the
positive impacts the letter writers describe. But I don’t want to dwell on that
in this post, or on the Piketty-Saez data, because I think the letters above
from Mr. Sutton and Mr. Swierczek make a more basic mistake. They may not find the change in income
inequality relevant, because their subtext is that inequality itself matters
much less than the income mobility that creates it. The subtext is if we diligently apply our “greater
talents, greater intelligence and the strong work ethic”, we will be rewarded
with a higher place on the income scale, so the station we hold in life is the
station we have fairly earned.
All of which sounds simple and compelling---and all of which is flatly
contradicted by the evidence of the real world.
The vision described by these two letter writers, which is a syrup of
classical economic theories so distilled and simplified that few classical
economists would swallow it straight, may describe some forces that are at work
in the economy, but there are clearly other forces at work at the same time. If this vision alone described the world then
differences in income inequality from one period of history to another, or from
one country to another, could be explained by changes in the degree to which
economic virtue is rewarded at different times and places. Hard work and talent would propel us farther,
and create larger income inequalities, when economic mobility was high than
when it was low, just as an object slides farther on ice than on asphalt.
But the by now well-known Great Gatsby
curve shows that exactly the opposite is true.
Higher income mobility between generations is associated with less income inequality, not more.
Here’s one version of the curve, from this
study by the Center for American Progress, written by economist Miles Corak:
This curve plots the level of inequality in developed
countries against the intergenerational income mobility in those
countries. Countries farther out along
the horizontal axis have more unequal
household income; in this chart, the United States has---or had, in 1985, when
the workers now reaching their peak earning years entered the workplace; this
data describes the income inequality of their parents---the highest level of
income inequality of all the countries shown.
And income inequality in the United States has exploded since 1985!
Countries higher on the vertical axis have a less income mobility between generations (or, put
differently, a higher impact of parent’s income in 1985 on current income of
their children reaching their peak earning years). A quick glance shows that the correlation is
just the reverse of that implied by Mr. Sutton and Mr. Swierczek . If they were right, then countries in which
your success depended only on your own worth and your own work rather than on
the advantages your parents could provide, countries in which income could “flow to
those with greater talents, greater intelligence and the strong work ethic to
use their God-given blessings” would have high income inequality, since
the economy would unequally reward hard work and effort. The upward slope of the fitted line shows
exactly the opposite.
The United States is among the most unequal and least mobile
societies in this group; only Italy and Great Britain have less economic
mobility between generations. The
American dream of rising from humble origins to great success, or at least
greater success than your parents experienced, is less likely in the United States than it is in Canada, or Australia,
or Sweden---and far less likely than in Finland, Norway or Denmark.
(To be fair, Mr. Swierczek does claim that in a free market with
nothing to restrict income mobility the striving of those lower on the income
scale to rise will cause income inequality to “self-correct”---but this must
mean that in his view Norway, Sweden and Denmark with their substantial welfare
states financed by high taxes have much freer markets than the United States
does, since their income inequality has “self corrected” while ours has not.)
Of course the existence of a correlation between income inequality
and income immobility does not imply that one causes the other, but it’s easy
to come up with arguments for causality in either direction. For example, income inequality may provide
incentive to succeed, but incentive alone is not enough: incentive must be
combined with opportunity, and opportunity is neither free nor distributed
equally across the population. Those who
begin with high family incomes can buy more of it, for themselves and for their
children, than those who do not. So
income inequality may create less income mobility.
It’s also possible that income immobility contributes, after
multiple generations, to increasing income inequality, simply by building
inequality between families as a residue over time. So less income mobility may create income
inequality.
It’s possible to look outside this graph for causation, too; there are clear correlations of each of these two variables with some third characteristic (race, for example, or education) that continues across generations. The “greater talents, greater intelligence and the strong work ethic” will have a smaller reward for those held back by discrimination on the basis of race, or gender, or religion, or any other characteristic, than for those who are not. Educated parents read to their children more, and instill respect for education in those children, so the children of educated parents do better and go farther in school. And other differences between wealthy and poor contribute to income inequality for at least one generation, such as family structure: poor families are more often single-parent households than rich families, and that fact may create more resources on average---a greater variety of adults to turn to---for the children who live in wealthy households.
So the path
to a more equal distribution of income may through a more equal distribution
of opportunity, and a more equal reward for the hard application of work, talent
and intelligence. I think Mr. Sutton might agree with that. He might support efforts to reduce the impact of racism, or sexism, on economic mobility.
But it’s also true that the path to a more equal distribution of opportunity and more equal reward for work and talent may run through a more equal distribution of income, and that no amount of effort to provide opportunity can compensate for the disadvantage of being born into a poor family in a culture with extreme income inequality. And that is the causal link that Mr. Sutton and Mr. Swierczek don't see, or don't want to see.
The point here is not that I have the answer; I emphatically don’t have any single answer. I suspect that every one of the elements I described above as contributing to immobility or inequality does contribute, and that there are many, many more that I didn’t mention. And nothing I've said here, no causal link I've suggested, explains the rapid increase in inequality, or the restoration of an income divergence rivaling the gilded age.
But it’s also true that the path to a more equal distribution of opportunity and more equal reward for work and talent may run through a more equal distribution of income, and that no amount of effort to provide opportunity can compensate for the disadvantage of being born into a poor family in a culture with extreme income inequality. And that is the causal link that Mr. Sutton and Mr. Swierczek don't see, or don't want to see.
The point here is not that I have the answer; I emphatically don’t have any single answer. I suspect that every one of the elements I described above as contributing to immobility or inequality does contribute, and that there are many, many more that I didn’t mention. And nothing I've said here, no causal link I've suggested, explains the rapid increase in inequality, or the restoration of an income divergence rivaling the gilded age.
The point instead is that, as ideologically or personally
satisfying as it may be to reduce the world to a one-dimensional explanation of
inequality, particularly one that regards it as natural or just, the real economic world
isn’t as simple as that. If either more
equal economic rewards or more dependable rewards to talent, intelligence,
creativity and strong work ethic matters to you, then you need to move beyond
personal gratification, or self-justification, or ideological zeal, beyond the
simplistic economic visions in the letters above. If these things matter, we need to create
them and preserve them, because they don’t, unfortunately, create or preserve
themselves.
Hum, I tried to comment but my text disappeared. I'll try again. First, brilliant as always. Second, it is about time you wrote something. Finally, I've posted it to my Facebook page to elucidate this matter for others.
ReplyDelete